Estudio Economistas Franceses entre ellos Quesnai.
Enviado por tomas • 2 de Febrero de 2018 • 2.442 Palabras (10 Páginas) • 323 Visitas
...
Law had indeed influenced French economists like M61on and
Dupr6 de St. Maur.f But Cantillon's work was almost exclusively
the source of the physiocrat doctrine that the application
of capital to agriculture is the sole fountain of aU
wealth. Besides this last representative of English physiocracy,
which was to a good extent a development of mercantilism,!
Hiune's essays (translated in 1754 into French) gave a
proof of the futility of the reigning doctrine of the balance of
trade. But his theory of the creation of wealth hy labor, the
outcome of Sir William Petty's doctrine of its production hy
population, which Cantillon had accepted and Miraheau had
subsequently introduced into his Ami des Sommes (1756), was
refuted hy Quesnay. For in France capital was wanting, and
the increase of population seemed to be the consequence, and
not the cause of it. This divergence from the English doctrine
is therefore to be ascribed to his observations, as set
forth in his articles.
• His suocesBful experiments are described by Henry Fatullo, Essai ntr I'JnUlioration
des Terres, 1768, p. 77.
tin the Ephimerides du Citoyen for 1769, U., p. 67, Dupont de Nemours
regrets that the wise principles and truths found in the works of Culpeper,
Locke, Decker, Child, and especially Joslah Tucker, had not become known
earlier.
tin an article on Cantillon, in the forthcoming DlMonary o/PoUticaZ Eoonomy,
edited by Mr. B. H. Inglis Faigrave, I shall Introduce such proofs as will
indicate his English nationality.
NOTES AND MEMORANDA lOS
The inference he drew was a negative one indeed: that
all economic reform must commence with putting aside all
restrictioDS on the exportation of corn, which occasioned a
want of outlet and the ruin of the rural population. But
such a negative programme could not be prescribed as a
cure for another national distress,— the financial confusion.
Machault, the controller of finances of 1750, was unable to create
order, and after him Silhouette gave a fatal blow to public
credit. His successor in 1760 found the treasury empty.
One vingti^me was raised after another. The parliaments
protested in vain agamst government vexations, but, in spite
of the public calamity, were unable to recommend other measures
than " economy in the necessary expenses."
Plans of financial reform, especially concerning the taille,
had been modelled a long time before. The levelling and
centralizing tendency of Louis XIV.'s administrative policy
had given its stamp to most of them. One of the first of
tbese "systems," the dime royale of Vauban, exhibits the
advantages of a tenth upon all estates whatever. Other
financial reformers were De la Jonchdre, Law, Boulainvilliers,
St. Pierre, and D'Argenson. But their projects,
even when introduced, like St. Pierre's, proved failures. They
were not founded upon a scientific knowledge of the objects
to be taxed, and, when calculated to remove the load from one
class of tax-payers, proved oppressive to another. But a
doctrine of taxation had been developed by Quesnay in his
articles in the JEncyclop&die. He had calculated the amount
and productivity of capital necessary to obtain a sound state
of agriculture. Capital, therefore, in its application to agriculture,
was to him the only means of obtaining a taxable
net produce. By means of this theory of income he could
proceed to build a natural system of finances, not an arbitrary
one, like that of his predecessors.
The letters accompanying the Tableau Economique, which
Quesnay sent to Mirabeau, show that such was the original
character of the physiocratic system. " I have tried," he says,
" to make a fundamental tableau of the economic system
[de Vor dre Sconomique'], ia order to represent consumption
and production in a manner easy of comprehension, and to
104 QUABTEBLY JOUBNAL OF ECONOMICS
permit of a clear judgment of the arrangements and disorders
tbe
...